Dividend discount model




The dividend discount model (DDM) is a method of valuing a company's stock price based on the theory that its stock is worth the sum of all of its future dividend payments, discounted back to their present value.[1] In other words, it is used to value stocks based on the net present value of the future dividends. The equation most widely used is called the Gordon growth model (GGM). It is named after Myron J. Gordon of the University of Toronto, who originally published it along with Eli Shapiro in 1956 and made reference to it in 1959.[2][3] Their work borrowed heavily from the theoretical and mathematical ideas found in John Burr Williams 1938 book "The Theory of Investment Value."


The variables are: P{displaystyle P}P is the current stock price. g{displaystyle g}g is the constant growth rate in perpetuity expected for the dividends. r{displaystyle r}r is the constant cost of equity capital for that company. D1{displaystyle D_{1}}D_{1} is the value of the next year's dividends.


P=D1r−g{displaystyle P={frac {D_{1}}{r-g}}}P={frac  {D_{1}}{r-g}}



Contents






  • 1 Derivation of equation


  • 2 Income plus capital gains equals total return


  • 3 Growth cannot exceed cost of equity


  • 4 Some properties of the model


  • 5 Problems with the model


  • 6 Related methods


  • 7 References


  • 8 Further reading


  • 9 External links





Derivation of equation


The model uses the fact that the current value of the dividend payment D0(1+g)t{displaystyle D_{0}(1+g)^{t}}{displaystyle D_{0}(1+g)^{t}} at (discrete ) time t{displaystyle t}t is D0(1+g)t(1+r)t{displaystyle {frac {D_{0}(1+g)^{t}}{{(1+r)}^{t}}}}{displaystyle {frac {D_{0}(1+g)^{t}}{{(1+r)}^{t}}}}, and so the current value of all the future dividend payments, which is the current price P{displaystyle P}P, is the sum of the infinite series


P0=∑t=1∞D0(1+g)t(1+r)t{displaystyle P_{0}=sum _{t=1}^{infty }{D_{0}}{frac {(1+g)^{t}}{(1+r)^{t}}}}{displaystyle P_{0}=sum _{t=1}^{infty }{D_{0}}{frac {(1+g)^{t}}{(1+r)^{t}}}}

This summation can be rewritten as


P0=D0r′(1+r′+r′2+r′3+....){displaystyle P_{0}={D_{0}}r'(1+r'+{r'}^{2}+{r'}^{3}+....)}{displaystyle P_{0}={D_{0}}r'(1+r'+{r'}^{2}+{r'}^{3}+....)}

where


r′=(1+g)(1+r).{displaystyle r'={frac {(1+g)}{(1+r)}}.}{displaystyle r'={frac {(1+g)}{(1+r)}}.}

The series in parenthesis is the geometric series with common ratio r′{displaystyle r'}r' so it sums to 11−r′{displaystyle {frac {1}{1-r'}}}{displaystyle {frac {1}{1-r'}}} if r′2<1{displaystyle r'^{2}<1}{displaystyle r'^{2}<1}. Thus,


P0=D0r′1−r′{displaystyle P_{0}={frac {D_{0}r'}{1-r'}}}{displaystyle P_{0}={frac {D_{0}r'}{1-r'}}}

Substituting the value for r′{displaystyle r'}r' leads to



P0=D0(1+g)(1+r)1−1+g1+r{displaystyle P_{0}={frac {frac {{D_{0}}(1+g)}{(1+r)}}{1-{frac {1+g}{1+r}}}}}{displaystyle P_{0}={frac {frac {{D_{0}}(1+g)}{(1+r)}}{1-{frac {1+g}{1+r}}}}},

which is simplified by multiplying by 1+r1+r{displaystyle {frac {1+r}{1+r}}}{frac  {1+r}{1+r}}, so that


P0=D0(1+g)r−g{displaystyle P_{0}={frac {D_{0}(1+g)}{r-g}}}{displaystyle P_{0}={frac {D_{0}(1+g)}{r-g}}}


Income plus capital gains equals total return


The DDM equation can also be understood to state simply that a stock's total return equals the sum of its income and capital gains.



D1r−g=P0{displaystyle {frac {D_{1}}{r-g}}=P_{0}}{displaystyle {frac {D_{1}}{r-g}}=P_{0}} is rearranged to give D1P0+g=r{displaystyle {frac {D_{1}}{P_{0}}}+g=r}{displaystyle {frac {D_{1}}{P_{0}}}+g=r}

Dividend Yield (D1/P0){displaystyle (D_{1}/P_{0})}{displaystyle (D_{1}/P_{0})} plus Growth (g) equal Cost of Equity (r)


Consider the dividend growth rate in the DDM model as a proxy for the growth of earnings and by extension the stock price and capital gains. Consider the DDM's cost of equity capital as a proxy for the investor's required total return.[4]


Income+Capital Gain=Total Return{displaystyle {text{Income}}+{text{Capital Gain}}={text{Total Return}}}{text{Income}}+{text{Capital Gain}}={text{Total Return}}


Growth cannot exceed cost of equity


From the first equation, one might notice that r−g{displaystyle r-g}r-g cannot be negative. When growth is expected to exceed the cost of equity in the short run, then usually a two-stage DDM is used:


P=∑t=1ND0(1+g)t(1+r)t+PN(1+r)N{displaystyle P=sum _{t=1}^{N}{frac {D_{0}left(1+gright)^{t}}{left(1+rright)^{t}}}+{frac {P_{N}}{left(1+rright)^{N}}}}P=sum _{{t=1}}^{N}{frac  {D_{0}left(1+gright)^{t}}{left(1+rright)^{t}}}+{frac  {P_{N}}{left(1+rright)^{N}}}

Therefore,


P=D0(1+g)r−g[1−(1+g)N(1+r)N]+D0(1+g)N(1+g∞)(1+r)N(r−g∞),{displaystyle P={frac {D_{0}left(1+gright)}{r-g}}left[1-{frac {left(1+gright)^{N}}{left(1+rright)^{N}}}right]+{frac {D_{0}left(1+gright)^{N}left(1+g_{infty }right)}{left(1+rright)^{N}left(r-g_{infty }right)}},}P={frac  {D_{0}left(1+gright)}{r-g}}left[1-{frac  {left(1+gright)^{N}}{left(1+rright)^{N}}}right]+{frac  {D_{0}left(1+gright)^{N}left(1+g_{infty }right)}{left(1+rright)^{N}left(r-g_{infty }right)}},

where g{displaystyle g}g denotes the short-run expected growth rate, g∞{displaystyle g_{infty }}g_{infty } denotes the long-run growth rate, and N{displaystyle N}N is the period (number of years), over which the short-run growth rate is applied.


Even when g is very close to r, P approaches infinity, so the model becomes meaningless.



Some properties of the model


a)
When the growth g is zero, the dividend is capitalized.



P0=D1r{displaystyle P_{0}={frac {D_{1}}{r}}}P_{0}={frac  {D_{1}}{r}}.

b)
This equation is also used to estimate the cost of capital by solving for r{displaystyle r}r.


r=D1P0+g.{displaystyle r={frac {D_{1}}{P_{0}}}+g.}r={frac  {D_{1}}{P_{0}}}+g.

c)
Which is equivalent to the formula of the Gordon Growth Model:



P0{displaystyle P_{0}}P_{0} = D1{displaystyle D_{1}}D_{1} / (k – g)

Where “P0{displaystyle P_{0}}P_{0}” stands for the present stock value, “D1{displaystyle D_{1}}D_{1}” stands for expected dividend per share one year from the present time, “g” stands for rate of growth of dividends, and “k” represents the required return rate for the equity investor.



Problems with the model


a)
The presumption of a steady and perpetual growth rate less than the cost of capital may not be reasonable.


b)
If the stock does not currently pay a dividend, like many growth stocks, more general versions of the discounted dividend model must be used to value the stock. One common technique is to assume that the Modigliani-Miller hypothesis of dividend irrelevance is true, and therefore replace the stocks's dividend D with E earnings per share. However, this requires the use of earnings growth rather than dividend growth, which might be different. This approach is especially useful for computing a residual value of future periods.


c)
The stock price resulting from the Gordon model is sensitive to the growth rate g{displaystyle g}g chosen.



Related methods


The dividend discount model is closely related to both discounted earnings and discounted cashflow models. In either of the latter two, the value of a company is based on how much money is made by the company. For example, if a company consistently paid out 50% of earnings as dividends, then the discounted dividends would be worth 50% of the discounted earnings. Also, in the dividend discount model, a company that does not pay dividends is worth nothing.



References





  1. ^ Investopedia – Digging Into The Dividend Discount Model


  2. ^ Gordon, M.J and Eli Shapiro (1956) "Capital Equipment Analysis: The Required Rate of Profit," Management Science, 3,(1) (October 1956) 102-110. Reprinted in Management of Corporate Capital, Glencoe, Ill.: Free Press of, 1959.


  3. ^ Gordon, Myron J. (1959). "Dividends, Earnings and Stock Prices". Review of Economics and Statistics. The MIT Press. 41 (2): 99–105. doi:10.2307/1927792. JSTOR 1927792..mw-parser-output cite.citation{font-style:inherit}.mw-parser-output q{quotes:"""""""'""'"}.mw-parser-output code.cs1-code{color:inherit;background:inherit;border:inherit;padding:inherit}.mw-parser-output .cs1-lock-free a{background:url("//upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/thumb/6/65/Lock-green.svg/9px-Lock-green.svg.png")no-repeat;background-position:right .1em center}.mw-parser-output .cs1-lock-limited a,.mw-parser-output .cs1-lock-registration a{background:url("//upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/thumb/d/d6/Lock-gray-alt-2.svg/9px-Lock-gray-alt-2.svg.png")no-repeat;background-position:right .1em center}.mw-parser-output .cs1-lock-subscription a{background:url("//upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/thumb/a/aa/Lock-red-alt-2.svg/9px-Lock-red-alt-2.svg.png")no-repeat;background-position:right .1em center}.mw-parser-output .cs1-subscription,.mw-parser-output .cs1-registration{color:#555}.mw-parser-output .cs1-subscription span,.mw-parser-output .cs1-registration span{border-bottom:1px dotted;cursor:help}.mw-parser-output .cs1-hidden-error{display:none;font-size:100%}.mw-parser-output .cs1-visible-error{font-size:100%}.mw-parser-output .cs1-subscription,.mw-parser-output .cs1-registration,.mw-parser-output .cs1-format{font-size:95%}.mw-parser-output .cs1-kern-left,.mw-parser-output .cs1-kern-wl-left{padding-left:0.2em}.mw-parser-output .cs1-kern-right,.mw-parser-output .cs1-kern-wl-right{padding-right:0.2em}


  4. ^ Spreadsheet for variable inputs to Gordon Model




Further reading




  • Gordon, Myron J. (1962). The Investment, Financing, and Valuation of the Corporation. Homewood, IL: R. D. Irwin.


  • "Equity Discounted Cash Flow Models" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2013-06-12.



External links


  • Alternative derivations of the Gordon Model and its place in the context of other DCF-based shortcuts








這個網誌中的熱門文章

12.7 cm/40 Type 89 naval gun

Shark

Wiciokrzew